The economy shows a number of
inconsistencies, said Roger Ferguson, chairman and chief executive of TIAA-CREF,
at the Council on Foreign Relations, in a talk about retirement in the 21st
century. As equities and bonds seem to
become more correlated, any talk of what markets will be most affected or how
smoothly they will absorb an interest-rate hike is all speculation, Ferguson
said. He is relatively optimistic about the so-called taper tantrum. The Fed
has been relatively transparent, and rates are likely to be raised gradually.
“Behind every headline is three or
four stories,” Ferguson said, and those can give a fuller picture to what seem
to be inconsistent data. Henny Sender, chief correspondent for the Financial Times, who presided, asked
Ferguson for some clarity around the clash between an improving labor market
and the low retail figures: “the worst since 2009,” she said.
Both households and business are
hit by the impact of a range of forces, Ferguson pointed out. In some
households, people are jobholders, while in others jobs aren’t paying what
they’d hoped. Some part-time workers wish they were working full-time, and some
on the fringes of the labor market are waiting to get back in. Some households
are deleveraging, he said, and defaults are rising again in the home equity
market. Those with exposure to the equities market have experienced quite a
rally, but not everyone has been lucky enough to participate.
NEXT:
Volatility could come from numbers pointing in different directions.
The internally inconsistent data
create volatility, Ferguson said. The labor market suggests strength, but some
factors in the market suggest weakness. As the data do not all point in one
direction, it could bring some bumps.
In actual monetary policy, there’s
some asynchronous movement as well: The Fed seems ready for takeoff, while some
banks are still thinking about quantitative easing—all playing out against a
backdrop of geopolitical change and uncertainty.
Ferguson said these factors would
likely spill over into markets and market expectations. “It won’t be smooth,”
he said, “but that will come from external factors—geopolitical changes and
uncertainty—and not from any absence of clarity on the part of the Fed.”
Companies may have more of an
incentive to engage in financial engineering and share buybacks rather than
investing in labor or capital equipment. “The facts are that business fixed
investment has been relatively subdued,” Ferguson said, noting that businesses
have been adding to their work forces. “They are investing in labor to some
degree, but it’s been moderately subdued. Topline growth, revenue growth has
been surprisingly slow. To get bottom-line growth, they have to manage expenses
very closely.”
In the current low interest-rate
environment, businesses have been taking this ample liquidity in the
marketplace and figuring out ways to overcome flat revenue growth. One answer
has been corporate transactions; the other is stock buyback to create total
shareholder return at a point where revenue expansion is hard to come by.
Ferguson points out that in a in a
consumer-driven economy—the U.S. has about 67% of its GDP around consumption,
he says—“when consumption is growing relatively slowly and the expectation for
shareholders is an increasing return, quarter over quarter, businesses are
looking for ways to do that using various techniques such as buybacks and
transactions.”
Ferguson said that the ranging nature of market stories
should come as no surprise. The unique situations of households and businesses
are all factors as we look into a possible change in status in monetary policy,
he concluded.
By using this site you agree to our network wide Privacy Policy.
Behavioral Finance Q&A with Shachar Kariv – Part 2
In the second half of a conversation with PLANADVISER, U.C. Berkeley Economics Department Chair Shachar Kariv discusses the importance of defining and driving “financial rationality” among workplace savers.
Shachar Kariv is the Benjamin N. Ward Professor of Economics
and the Economics Department Chair at the University of California, Berkeley.
Like other thought leaders, Kariv believes behavioral finance is redefining the
way people save and invest money, especially for retirement.
He admits retirement readiness and decision theory aren’t
exactly the standard fare for economists in his position—but the trillions of
dollars Americans have saved in the form of tax-qualified retirement assets
comprise a critical piece of the U.S. investing landscape, he says. Beyond
this, it is vital for a healthy economic future that Americans save enough to
take financial responsibility for themselves and their families in retirement.
Finally—unlike economic challenges that so commonly break
down by income quartile or political affiliation—everyone who hopes to retire
one day, at any income level, must confront the difficult task of giving up
resources today for the benefit of one’s future self.
Q: Why do you think the fields of financial services and
retirement planning are only now getting serious about the role of behavioral
psychology and decision architecture?
Well, these ideas have been around for a long time, but
they are becoming more important in a world where financial services consumers
drive their own choices and are presented with so much more choice and control
than they had in the past.
The underlying ideas are not new. The first American
Nobel Laureate in economics was the great Paul Samuelson, who worked for a long
time out of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. In 1947 he wrote a book
called Foundations of Economic Analysis. Now, the titles of most
books in our field tend to oversell the content in the book—but this is an apt
title for the work Samuelson accomplished in his writing about modern economics
and financial decisionmaking.
It remains foundational today—he basically laid the
ground for what we talked about earlier as the Theory of Revealed Preferences.
He sketched out some of the earliest models that we can use to see what
people’s preferences are when it comes to allocating risk—and he was big on the
idea of letting the data reveal this, of looking at people’s real historical
choices and behaviors to distill or boil down their true preferences.
Moreover, he did something even more interesting for the
context of this conversation. He suggested that many market
participants—individuals and institutions—do not actually have any consistent
risk preferences to reveal. This will be familiar to your plan sponsor and
adviser readers. Some participants in plans are simply incoherent about their
own financial situation, so they are unable to rationally or consistently solve
the various trade-offs at work in financial decisionmaking. This is one of the
challenges the defined contribution retirement planning model is running
straight into today.
Q: Is it right to assume that participants who struggle
with defining their risk preferences will always do worse in the savings effort?
Not necessarily, and I’ll explain. One of the attacks most
commonly leveled against economists and certain economic theories is that we
make our judgements based on the assumption that the financial choices people
make are driven by their rationality. I think this is unfair criticism, because
any good economist knows people often rely on emotions or they simply make an
uninformed choice when it comes to their finances. Solid economic theory takes
this into account.
Another important thing to keep in mind is that, as
economists, we’re not talking about rationality in the common usage—most people
do not really know what economists mean when they talk about “rationality.”
They equate the rational choice with the objectively best choice—but that is
not what we are talking about in economics. The definition of rationality for
economists goes like this: “You are a rational financial market participant if
you have preferences that guide your behavior.”
You can see from this that an individual might have a
preference that works against his ultimate best interest—for example he may
take on less investment risk than he needs to have a good chance of funding an
adequate income replacement ratio in retirement—but by our definition this does
not mean he is irrational.
I think it is good in general for people to have reasons
underlying their economic decisions, but having this element of rationality
does not always or even generally mean that an individual will make the right
or the best decision based on their objective circumstances. In fact, it can be
more challenging to get a rational person on track in the retirement savings
effort than it is to get an irrational person on track. If the former has
strong psychological biases underlying his reason-driven decisionmaking, it
will be hard for a plan sponsor or adviser to push him towards the more
appropriate choice.
Q: Can you talk more about how this applies to the daily work of plan sponsors and advisers?
As you know, a lot of the ongoing theoretical work in behavioral finance and retirement plan services more broadly is dedicated to some form of the rationality question—and whether participants should have decisions made for them. This is an area where I am working with a firm called Capital Preferences to really build out a sensible approach for addressing this thinking in the real world of retirement plan administration. For us, the important step for plan sponsors and advisers to take is to try and define how rational their plan participants are, and then to think about what the answer might mean for important plan design decisions.
At Capital Preferences, we are able to deliver this type of an insight because of the careful construction of the "risk and ambiguity” games we use in place of things like portfolio risk questionnaires. In our games, we ask individuals to make a series of theoretical decisions, which are loosely structured like retirement investments. Importantly, we structure the series questions in the game so that, if a person is answering their questions in a rational way and according to a fixed set of principals held in the mind, there should be a pattern in their answers that bears this out.
I’ll give you an example. If you were a rational financial decisionmaker and you told me in one of these games that you preferred a given Portfolio A over another Portfolio B, and then you went on to tell me that you also preferred Portfolio C over Portfolio B, you should not then go on to tell me that you preferred Portfolio C over Portfolio A. When we run a person through a series of these tests like this, we very quickly start to see just how much inconsistency (i.e., irrationality) a given individual displays.
If I’m a financial adviser or a plan sponsor, and I see that you answer all these questions rationally, the question then becomes, does this person’s set of preferences line up with what I believe is their best interest? If so—great—but if not, are there steps I can take from a plan design or educational perspective that will better align one’s preference with one’s best interest?
If a participant, on the other hand, displays a lot of inconsistency, we have to ask how we can help the individual better understand their own circumstances and their wants and needs. Then we can turn to aligning their rationality and their best interest.
Q: Do you think the movement of this thinking into the financial services mainstream will improve the defined contribution retirement system and lead to more retirement wealth?
There are a few observations we can make that would suggest improving economic rationality will boost retirement plan performance in general. I explain this by first noting that U.S. households with very similar demographic characteristics across metrics like age, location, yearly income and the number of family members—they tend to vary quite widely in terms of their current wealth and their perception of financial well-being or anticipated hardship in retirement.
The question is, then, how can we explain the wealth stratification when these families are working off the same income base and presumably are facing the same expense demands? Outside of academia people are satisfied to say one’s success in wealth accumulation will be determined by the quality of their financial decisions—in the end the people that make higher quality financial decisions will accumulate more wealth. This sounds like a good explanation—but academics like myself, we want to go deeper. What does it actually mean to make financial decisions that are of high quality?
It’s not a concept that is very well defined at present—not least because people have very different goals for how much money they would like to make and how much money they need to be “happy” or “successful.” The key insight we have found after running many of these risk and ambiguity analyses is that, even after we control for income levels and other important factors, our measure of economic rationality helps explain the wealth stratification in a way other factors can’t.
“The scientific way of saying this: ‘One standard deviation from the mean score of consistency with economic rationality in our experiments is associated with 15% more household wealth.’ In other words, the more consistency one displays in financial decision making, the better off we would expect them to be.”